Why is discount rate important




















Depending upon the context, the discount rate has two distinct definitions and usages. Commercial banks in the U. They can borrow and loan money to other banks without the need for any collateral using the market-driven interbank rate. They also can borrow the money for their short-term operating requirements from the Federal Reserve Bank. Federal Reserve loans are processed through 12 regional branches of the Fed. This Fed-offered lending facility is known as the discount window.

The loans are extremely short-term: 24 hours or less. The rate of interest charged is the standard discount rate. This discount rate is set by the boards of the Federal Reserve Bank and is approved by its Board of Governors. The Fed's discount window program runs three tiers of loans, each of them using a separate but related rate.

The bank needs to maintain a certain level of security or collateral against the loan. Borrowing institutions use this facility sparingly, mostly when they cannot find willing lenders in the marketplace. The Fed-offered discount rates are available at relatively high-interest rates compared to the interbank borrowing rates. Discount loans are intended to be primarily an emergency option for banks in distress. Borrowing from the Fed discount window can even signal weakness to other market participants and investors.

Its use peaks during periods of financial distress. The use of the Fed's discount window soared in late and in , as financial conditions deteriorated sharply and the central bank took steps to inject liquidity into the financial system.

The discount rates for the first two tiers are determined independently by the Fed. The rate for the third tier is based on the prevailing rates in the market. In August , the Board of Governors cut the primary discount rate from 6. Owing to the financial crisis, the board also extended the lending period from overnight to 30 days, and then to 90 days in March Once the economy regained control, those temporary measures were revoked, and the discount rate was reverted to overnight lending only.

Outside the U. While the Fed maintains its own discount rate under the discount window program in the U. For instance, the European Central Bank offers standing facilities that serve as marginal lending facilities.

Financial organizations can obtain overnight liquidity from the central bank against the presentation of sufficient eligible assets as collateral. Most commonly, the Fed's discount window loans are overnight only, but in periods of extreme economic distress, such as the credit crisis, the loan period can be extended.

The same term, discount rate, is used in discounted cash flow DCF analysis. DCF is used to estimate the value of an investment based on its expected future cash flows.

Based on the concept of the time value of money , DCF analysis helps assess the viability of a project or investment by calculating the present value of expected future cash flows using a discount rate. Such an analysis begins with an estimate of the investment that a proposed project will require.

Then, the future returns it is expected to generate are considered. Using the discount rate, it is possible to calculate the current value of all such future cash flows. If the net present value is positive, the project is considered viable. If it is negative, the project isn't worth the investment. In this context of DCF analysis, the discount rate refers to the interest rate used to determine the present value.

Thus, present value is the value today of a stream of payments, receipts, or costs occurring over time, as discounted through the use of an interest rate. Present value calculations of benefits and costs are then compared to determine benefit-cost ratios.

Any benefit-cost ratio in excess of 1. Note that values used for benefit-cost analysis are often amortized over the project time horizon, yielding annualized benefits and costs. This practice allows for comparison of projects with different timeframes. The following example illustrates how the equation is used. Here is how we would calculate the present value of that benefit, assuming a 3 percent discount rate. The present value will vary widely based on the discount rate used in the analysis.

High discount rates, therefore, tend to discourage projects that generate long-term benefits e. Another way of thinking about discount rates is as the inverse of compound interest. That is, whereas compounding measures how much present-day investments will be worth in the future, discounting measures how much future benefits are worth today.

Discounting reflects how individuals value economic resources. Empirical evidence suggests that humans value immediate or near-term resources at higher levels than those acquired in the distant future NOAA Thus, discounting has been introduced to address the issues raised by the existence of this phenomenon, which is known as time preference.

Time preference is of significant interest to economists but the weight it is given depends on the discount rates used to perform present-value calculations. To understand better how time preference works, consider the perspective of the residents who fund a local public project. Most residents would exhibit some degree of impatience and value short-term benefits more highly than those that accrue over the long-term.

For example, some of the current residents who bear the costs of the project may die or move out of the local area before the long-term benefits are realized. Many of the benefits would accrue to individuals who later move into the area but played no part in the funding of the project.

It may not be possible or practical for those who invested in the project to receive compensation from the ultimate beneficiaries. In addition to time reference, there are a number of justifications for discounting the value of future benefits and costs.

First, inflation is common within most economies. Inflation is a sustained increase in the general price level. The rate of inflation reflects the pace at which general prices are increasing. Deflation is the opposite of inflation or a sustained decline in the general price levels. Deflation rarely occurs. In fact, the last period of sustained deflation in the United States occurred during the Great Depression between and Thus, economists are generally concerned with real, as opposed to nominal, values.

Nominal values reflect value without accounting for inflation or applying a discount rate. The real value of a benefit is equal to its nominal value adjusted for inflation. The real discount rate is the nominal rate minus the expected rate of inflation.

Inflation is a primary reason for discounting; however, independent of inflation, discounting is an import tool for assessing environmental benefit streams. Discount rates also reflect the opportunity cost of capital.

The opportunity cost of capital is the expected financial return forgone by investing in a project rather than in comparable financial securities. Therefore, discount rates reflect the forgone interest earning potential of the capital invested in the public project. The real opportunity cost of capital is often considered to be higher than the pure time preference rate. Third, public projects involve uncertainty and risk. When public projects are undertaken, including those that involve coastal or wetland restoration, there is a chance that future benefits will not be fully realized or realized at a higher level than estimated there are also uncertainties associated with costs.

For example, natural disaster could undermine efforts to restore wetland habitat, thus reducing or eliminating the future benefits that a restoration project would have generated. The further out into the future these benefits are expected to be realized, the greater the risk that some unexpected event or factor will occur and diminish the value of the future benefit.

Usually, the preferred method for dealing with uncertainty is directly to adjust benefits and costs or to perform the analysis quantifying the uncertainty and explicitly considering it in the estimates of benefits and costs , not change the discount rate. Fourth, humans prefer near-term to future benefits. The inability to defer gratification results in decisions that are slanted toward obtaining near-term benefits, often at the cost of those available in the long-term.

Regardless of whether this represents a sound policy, economic value is established based on human preferences, and humans prefer near-term benefits to those that accrue in the distant future see An Economic View of the Environment. For these and other reasons, there is general agreement among economists that discounting is necessary when comparing a stream of benefits and costs accruing over a number of years.

The discount rate is a key determinant in the outcome of a benefit-cost or damage valuation study. Therefore, it is important to understand the rationale for choosing one discount rate over another. At one extreme, an infinitely high discount rate would render all future actions meaningless. At the other extreme, using no discount rate means that benefits today are no more valuable than benefits experienced years from now.

Neither of these extreme views is correct. The real question is, "What discount rate best reflects the time preference, productivity, and risk of this project? Some philosophers and ethicists and some economists argue that present generations have the moral obligation to protect the interests of future generations, because these future recipients of benefits are as yet unborn and cannot express their own future preferences.

A more optimistic counterargument is that investments made in the economy today are likely to increase the future wealth of our descendents, giving them greater scope to exercise any preferences for environmental protection, so long as environmental damage is reversible see Irreversibility, Sustainability, Safe Minimum Standard.

The argument follows that a zero discount rate would ensure intergenerational equity by preventing the present generations from ignoring the long-term environmental and other consequences of present-day economic activity. Proponents of the zero discount rate argue that discounting can almost entirely devalue the economic impact of even catastrophic environmental events occurring outside a year time horizon.

For example, the present value of a catastrophic event occurring 50 years from today would be valued at less than 1 percent of its future value assuming a 10 percent discount rate. The ethical arguments against discounting are compelling; however, the existence of inflation, time preference, and the opportunity cost of capital suggests that a positive discount rate better reflects societal preferences.

The social rate of time preference is the rate at which society is willing to substitute present for future consumption of natural resources. The federal opportunity cost of capital and the rate of productivity growth are commonly used as proxies for the social rate of time preference. At the height of the financial crisis in , loans with the discount rate were as long as 90 days. The discounted rate of return — also called the discount rate and unrelated to the above definition — is the expected rate of return for an investment.

Also known as the cost of capital or required rate of return, it estimates current value of an investment or business based on its expected future cash flow. Taking into account the time value of money , the discount rate describes the interest percentage that an investment may yield over its lifetime. The discount rate allows investors and other to consider risk in an investment and set a benchmark for future investments.

This is helpful if you want to invest today, but need a certain amount later. The discount rate is often a precise figure, but it is still an estimate. It often involves making assumptions about future developments without taking into account all of the variables. For many investments, the discount rate is just an educated guess. While, some investments have predictable returns, future capital costs and returns from other investments vary.



0コメント

  • 1000 / 1000